Ekonomika ISSN 1392-1258 eISSN 2424-6166

2021, vol. 100(1), pp. 54–66 DOI: https://doi.org/10.15388/Ekon.2021.1.3

Negative Real Balance Effects in the Presence of Involuntary Unemployment

Yasuhito Tanaka
Faculty of Economics, Doshisha University, Japan
Email: yatanaka@mail.doshisha.ac.jp

Abstract. We examine the existence of negative real balance effects (or so-called Pigou effects) by falls in the nominal wage rate and the prices of the goods in situations where there is involuntary unemployment using a three-generations overlapping generations model, with a childhood period and pay-as-you go pension system for the older generation of consumers. We will show that if the net savings of the younger generation of consumers are larger than their debts due to consumption in their childhood period, there exists a positive real balance effect, and employment increases by a fall in the nominal wage rate; on the other hand, if the net savings of the younger generation of consumers are smaller than their debts, there exists a negative real balance effect, and employment decreases by a fall in the nominal wage rate.
Keywords: negative real balance effects, involuntary unemployment, three-generations overlapping generations model.

Received: 24/11/2020. Revised: 24/12/2020. Accepted: 03/02/2021
Copyright © 2021
Yasuhito Tanaka. Published by Vilnius University Press
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the
Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

1. Introduction

In this paper we examine the existence of negative real balance effects (or so-called Pigou effects) by falls in the nominal wage rate and the prices of the goods in situations where there is involuntary unemployment. The positive real balance effect works when the real assets of consumers increase due to falls in the nominal wage rate and the prices promote their consumption. Then, involuntary unemployment, due to lack of demand, could be reduced naturally. However, as Kalecki (1944) said in his comments to Pigou (1943), the positive real balance effect may not work or may work in reverse when people’s debts are greater than their assets.

Involuntary unemployment is a phenomenon when workers are willing to work at the market wage or just below but are prevented by factors beyond their control, mainly, the deficiency of aggregate demand. Umada (1997) derived an upward-sloping labor demand curve from the mark-up principle for firms and argued that such an upward-sloping labor demand curve leads to the existence of involuntary unemployment without wage rigidity. But his model of firm behavior is ad-hoc1. Otaki (2009) assumes the indivisibility of labor supply and has shown the existence of involuntary unemployment using efficient wage bargaining according to McDonald and Solow (1981). The arguments of this paper do not depend on bargaining. If labor supply is indivisible, it may be 1 or 0. On the other hand, if it is divisible, it takes a real value between 0 and 1. As discussed in Otaki (2015) (Theorem 2.3) and Otaki (2012), if labor supply is divisible and very small, no unemployment exists2. However, we show that even if labor supply is divisible, unless it is so small, there may exist involuntary unemployment. We consider consumers’ utility maximization and firms’ profit maximization in an overlapping generations (OLG) model under monopolistic competition according to Otaki (2007, 2009, 2011, 2015). We extend Otaki’s model to a three-generations OLG model with a childhood period, and we also consider the pay-as-you-go pension system for the older generation of consumers. We show that in such a model there can be a positive or negative real balance effect in situations where there is involuntary unemployment.

In the next section we explain the model and analyze consumers’ utility maximization and firms’ profit maximization. In Section 3 we show the following results (Proposition 1).

1. If the net savings of the younger generation of consumers are larger than their debts due to consumption in their childhood period, there exists a positive real balance effect, and employment increases by a fall in the nominal wage rate.
2. If the net savings of the younger generation consumers are smaller than their debts, there exists a negative real balance effect and, employment decreases by a fall in the nominal wage rate.

In Section 4, we discuss the role of fiscal policy in a situation where COVID-19 is prevalent.

2. The model and behaviors of agents

2.1. Consumers’ utility maximization

We consider a three-periods (0: childhood, 1: younger or working, and 2: older or retired) OLG model under monopolistic competition. It is a re-arrangement and an extension of the model put forth by Otaki (2007, 2009, 2015). The structure of our model is as follows.

1. There is one factor of production, labor, and there is a continuum of perishable goods indexed by z ∈ [0,1]. Good z is monopolistically produced by firm z with constant returns to scale technology.
2. Consumers consume the goods during the childhood period (Period 0). This consumption is covered by borrowing money from (employed) consumers of the younger generation and/or scholarship. They must repay these debts in their Period 1. However, unemployed consumers cannot repay their own debts. Therefore, we assume that unemployed consumers receive unemployment benefits from the government, which are covered by taxes on employed consumers of the younger generation.
3. During Period 1, consumers supply l units of labor, repay the debts and save money for their consumption in Period 2. They also pay taxes for the pay-as-you go pension system for the older generation.
4. During Period 2, consumers consume the goods using their savings carried over from their Period 1 earnings and receive the pay-as-you go pension, which is a lump-sum payment. It is covered by taxes on employed consumers of the younger generation.
5. Consumers determine their consumptions in Periods 1 and 2 and the labor supply at the beginning of Period 1. We assume that their consumption during the childhood period is constant.

Further we make the following assumptions.

Ownership of the firms. Each consumer inherits ownership of the firms from the previous generation. Corporate profits are distributed equally to consumers of the younger generation.

Zero interest rate. We assume a zero interest rate and that the repayment of debts of consumers is assured. Consumers’ borrowing in the childhood period is constant. If the savings of consumers in the younger period are insufficient for the borrowing, the government lends the scholarship to consumers in the childhood period. Consumers in the younger period are indifferent between lending money to childhood period consumers and savings by money.

Due to the existence of pay-as-you-go pension, the savings are likely to be insufficient for borrowing when consumption by consumers in the childhood period is not so small.

Notation

We use the following notation.

form_1.pdf: consumption basket of an employed consumer in Period i, i = 1,2.

form_1.pdf: consumption basket of an unemployed consumer in Period i, i = 1,2.

form_1.pdf: consumption of good z of an employed consumer in Period i, i = 1,2.

form_1.pdf: consumption of good z of an unemployed consumer in Period i, i = 1,2.

D: consumption basket of an individual in the childhood period, which is constant.

Pi: the price of consumption basket in Period i, i = 1,2.

pi(z): the price of good z in Period i, i = 1,2.

form_1.pdf: (expected) inflation rate (plus one).

W: nominal wage rate.

R: unemployment benefit for an unemployed individual. R = D.

form_1.pdf: consumption basket in the childhood period of a next generation consumer.

Q: pay-as-you-go pension for an individual of the older generation.

Θ: tax payment by an employed individual for the unemployment benefit.

form_1.pdf: pay-as-you-go pension for an individual of the younger generation when he retires.

Ψ: tax payment by an employed individual for the pay-as-you-go pension.

Π: profits of firms which are equally distributed to each consumer.

l: labor supply of an individual.

Γ(l): disutility function of labor, which is increasing and convex.

L: total employment.

Lf: population of labor or employment in the full-employment state.

y: labor productivity.

We assume that the population Lf is constant. We also assume that the nominal wage rate is constant in this section. We examine the effects of a change in the nominal wage rate in Section 3.

We consider a two-step method to solve the utility maximization of consumers, such that:

1. Employed and unemployed consumers maximize their utility by determining consumption baskets in Periods 1 and 2 given their income over two periods.
2. Then, they maximize their consumption baskets given the expenditure in each period.

Since the taxes for unemployed consumers’ unemployment benefits are paid by employed consumers of the same generation, D(= R) and Θ satisfy

D(Lf – L) = LΘ.

This means

L(D + Θ) =Lf D.

The price of the consumption basket in Period 0 is assumed to be 1. Thus, D is the real value of the consumption in the childhood period of consumers.

Also, since the taxes for the pay-as-you-go pension system are paid by employed consumers of the younger generation, Q and Ψ satisfy the following relationship:

LΨ = Lf Q

The utility function of employed consumers of one generation over three periods is

form_2.pdf

We assume that u(⋅) is a homothetic utility function. The utility function of unemployed consumers is

form_2.pdf

The consumption baskets of employed and unemployed consumers in Period i are

form_2.pdf

and

form_2.pdf

σ is the elasticity of substitution among the goods, and σ > 1.

The price of consumption basket in Period i is

form_2.pdf

The budget constraint for an employed consumer is

form_2.pdf

The budget constraint for an unemployed consumer is

form_2.pdf

Let

form_2.pdf

and

form_3.pdf

Since the utility functions form_3.pdf and form_3.pdf are homothetic, α is determined by the relative price form_3.pdf, and do not depend on the income of the consumers. Therefore, we have

form_3_a.pdf

and

form_3_a.pdf

From the first order conditions and the budget constraints for employed and unemployed consumers we obtain the following demand functions for consumption baskets.

form_3_a.pdf (1)

form_3_a.pdf

form_3_a.pdf

and

form_3_a.pdf

Solving maximization problems in Step 2, the following demand functions of employed and unemployed consumers are derived3.

form_3_a.pdf

and

form_4.pdf

From these analyses we obtain the indirect utility functions of employed and unemployed consumers as follows:

form_4.pdf

and

form_4.pdf

Let

form_4.pdf

Then, since the real value of D in the childhood period is constant, we can write

form_4.pdf

and

form_4.pdf

ω is the real wage rate. Denote

form_4.pdf

The condition for maximization of Ve with respect to l given ρ is

form_4.pdf (2)

where

form_4.pdf

Given P1 and ρ the labor supply is a function of ω. From (2) we get

form_4.pdf

If form_4.pdf, the labor supply is increasing with respect to the real wage rate ω.

2.2. Firms’ profit maximization

Let d1(z) be the total demand for good z by younger generation consumers in Period 1. Then,

form_4.pdf

This is the sum of the demand of employed and unemployed consumers. Note that form_4.pdf is the pay-as-you-go pension for younger generation consumers in their Period 2. Similarly, their total demand for good z in Period 2 is written as

form_4.pdf

Let form_4.pdf be the demand for good z by the older generation. Then,

form_5.pdf

where form_5.pdf and form_5.pdf are the nominal wage rate, the profits of firms, the employment, the individual labor supply, the debt of an individual, and the pay-as-you-go pension, respectively, during the previous period. form_5.pdf is the value of α for the older generation. We assume form_5.pdf. Q is the pay-as-you-go pension for consumers of the older generation themselves. Let

form_5.pdf

This is the total savings or the total consumption of the older generation consumers including the pay-as-you-go pensions they receive in their Period 2. It is the planned consumption that is determined in Period 1 of the older generation consumers. Net savings is the difference between M and the pay-as-you-go pensions in their Period 2, as follows:

MLf Q.

Their demand for good z is written as form_5.pdf. Government expenditure constitutes the national income as well as the consumptions of the younger and older generations. It is financed by the tax on the younger generation consumers. Then, the total demand for good z is written as

form_5.pdf (3)

where Y is the effective demand defined by

form_5.pdf

Note that form_5.pdf is consumption in the childhood period of a next generation consumer. G is the government expenditure, except for the pay-as-you-go pensions, scholarships and unemployment benefits, and T is the tax revenue for the government expenditure (except for the pay-as-you-go pensions and unemployment benefits). See Otaki (2007, 2015) about this demand function.

Let L and Ll be employment and the “employment × labor supply” of firm z. The output of firm z is Lly. At the equilibrium Lly = d(z). Then, we have

form_5.pdf

From (3)

form_5.pdf

Thus,

form_5.pdf

The profit of firm z is

form_5.pdf

The condition for profit maximization is

form_5.pdf

Therefore, we obtain

form_5.pdf

This means that the real wage rate is

form_6.pdf

Since all firms are symmetric,

form_6.pdf

3. Positive or negative real balance effect with involuntary unemployment

The (nominal) aggregate supply of the goods is equal to

form_6.pdf

The (nominal) aggregate demand is

form_6.pdf

Since they are equal in the equilibrium,

form_6.pdf (4)

Ll cannot be larger than Lf l. However, it may be strictly smaller than Lf l. We then have L < Lf and involuntary unemployment exists.

We assume a balanced budget, that is, G = T, and consider the steady state where the employment, the output, the nominal wage rate, and the prices of the goods are constant. In such a state we can assume form_6.pdf and form_6.pdf. Then, from (4) the savings of the younger generation consumers are

form_6.pdf

This means that the steady state with constant employment and prices is maintained by the balanced budget.

Now suppose that corresponding to the existence of involuntary unemployment the nominal wage rate and the prices of the goods fall at the rate ρ – 1 < 0. Let L' be the employment in this case. If the price changes are correctly predicted by the consumers and the government, we can assume form_6.pdf and form_6.pdf. Then, (4) is rewritten as

form_6.pdf.

The savings of the younger generation consumers are

form_6.pdf (5)

We find that if

form_6.pdf (6)

(5) is larger than ρM. Then, since the marginal propensity to consume, α, is constant, we have L' > L, that is, the employment increases by a fall in the nominal wage rate. On the other hand, if

form_6.pdf (7)

(5) is smaller than ρM. Then, L' < L, and the employment decreases by a fall in the nominal wage rate. (6) means that the net savings of the younger generation consumers, – Lf Q, are larger than their debts, Lf D. In this case there exists positive real balance effect. On the other hand, (7) means that the net savings of the younger generation consumers are smaller than their debts. In that case there exists negative real balance effect.

The results of this paper are summarized in the following proposition.

1. If the net savings of the younger generation consumers are larger than their debts due to consumption in their childhood period, we have M – Lf D – Lf Q > 0, and there exists a positive real balance effect, and employment increases by a fall in the nominal wage rate.
2. If the net savings of the younger generation consumers are smaller than their debts, we have M – Lf D – Lf Q < 0, and there exists a negative real balance effect, and employment decreases by a fall in the nominal wage rate.

4. Fiscal Policy

(4) implies

form_7.pdf

This means that the aggregate demand is determined by the government expenditure G given the savings of the older generation consumers, taxes, pay-as-you go pensions and so on. With COVID-19 prevalent in many countries around the world, economic activity is likely to remain sluggish, and involuntary unemployment is likely to increase. With a negative real balance effect, a decline in wage rates will not help the economy to recover. In such a situation, an effective policy to restore depressed economic activity is to increase aggregate demand through an aggressive fiscal policy using government debt or seigniorage.

5. Concluding Remarks

Using a three-generations overlapping generations model, we have shown that whether the real balance effect is positive or negative depends on whether the net savings of consumers are greater or less than their debts. In this paper we assume that the goods are produced by only labor. In the future research we want to analyze real balance effects in situations where the goods are produced by capital and labor and there are investments by firms.

Appendix: Calculations of the second step of consumers’
utility maximization

Lagrange functions in the second step for employed and unemployed consumers are

form_7.pdf (A.1)

form_8.pdf

and

form_8.pdf

form_8.pdf and form_8.pdf are Lagrange multipliers.

The first order condition for (A.1) is

form_8.pdf (A.2)

From this

form_8.pdf

Then,

form_8.pdf It means

form_8.pdf

and so

form_8.pdf

From (A.2)

form_8.pdf

Then,

form_8.pdf

Therefore,

form_8.pdf

Similarly,

form_8.pdf

Thus,

form_8.pdf

and from (1) we obtain

form_8.pdf

By (A.2)

form_8.pdf

From this we get

form_9.pdf

form_9.pdf and form_9.pdf are similarly obtained.

References

G. D. Hansen. Indivisible labor and business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 16:309–327, 1985.

M. Kalecki. The classical stationary state’’ A comment, Economic Journal, 54: 131–132, 1944.

M. Lavoie. Efficiency wages in Kaleckian models of employment. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 23:449–464, 2001.

I. M. McDonald and R. M. Solow. Wage bargaining and employment. American Economic Review, 71:896–908, 1981.

M. Otaki. The dynamically extended Keynesian cross and the welfare-improving fiscal policy. Economics Letters, 96:23–29, 2007.

M. Otaki. A welfare economics foundation for the full-employment policy. Economics Letters, 102:1–3, 2009.

M. Otaki. The aggregation problem in the employment theory: The representative individual model or individual employees model? (https://www.scirp.org/journal/paperinformation.aspx?paperid=25920). Theoretical Economics Letters, 2:530–533, 2012.

M. Otaki. Keynesian Economics and Price Theory: Re-orientation of a Theory of Monetary Economy. Springer, 2015.

A. C. Pigou, The classical stationary state, Economic Journal, 53:343–351, 1943.

Y. Tanaka. Indivisible labor supply and involuntary unemployment: monopolistic competition model. The Singapore Economic Review, forthcoming, 2020a.

T. Umada. On the existence of involuntary unemployment (hi-jihatsuteki-shitsugyo no sonzai ni tsuite (in Japanese)). Yamaguchi Keizaigaku Zasshi, 45(6):61–73, 1997.

1 Lavie (2001) presented a similar analysis.

2 About indivisible labor supply also please see Hansen (1985). In Tanaka (2020) involuntary unemployment under indivisible labor supply is analyzed.

3 Calculations of the maximization problems in Step 2 are standard using Lagrange multiplier method. Please see Appendix abut details.